Session 1: Introduction to Difference-in-Differences
October 28, 2031
\(\newcommand{\E}{\mathbb{E}} \newcommand{\E}{\mathbb{E}} \newcommand{\var}{\mathrm{var}} \newcommand{\cov}{\mathrm{cov}} \newcommand{\Var}{\mathrm{var}} \newcommand{\Cov}{\mathrm{cov}} \newcommand{\Corr}{\mathrm{corr}} \newcommand{\corr}{\mathrm{corr}} \newcommand{\L}{\mathrm{L}} \renewcommand{\P}{\mathrm{P}} \newcommand{\independent}{{\perp\!\!\!\perp}} \newcommand{\indicator}[1]{ \mathbf{1}\{#1\} } \newcommand{\T}{T}\)
Introduction to Difference-in-Differences
DID Basics in 2 Period Case
Staggered Treatment Adoption
Application/Code for Minimum Wage Policy
Including Covariates in the Parallel Trends Assumption
Common Extensions for Empirical Work
Dealing with More Complicated Treatment Regimes
Alternative Identification Strategies
Additional Workshop Materials: https://bcallaway11.github.io/bank-of-portugal/
References:
Callaway (2023), Handbook of Labor, Human Resources and Population Economics
Baker, Callaway, Cunningham, Goodman-Bacon, Sant’Anna (2024), draft posted very soon
Exploit a data structure where the researcher observes:
Multiple periods of data
Some pre-treatment data for all units
Some units become treated while other units remain untreated
(In my view) this particular data setup is a key distinguishing feature of difference-in-differences approaches relative to traditional panel data models (i.e., fixed effects, dynamic panel, etc.)
Running Example: Causal effects of a state-level minimum wage increase on employment
Widely studied using DID identification strategies (Card and Krueger (1994), many others)
For today: very simplified version with (1) no changes in federal minimum wage and (2) “binarized” state minimum wages (i.e., state minimum wage is either above the federal minimum wage or not)
Panel data gives researchers the opportunity to follow the same person, firm, location, etc. over multiple time periods
Having this sort of data seems fundamentally useful for learning about causal effects of some treatment/policy variable.
To see this, the fundamental problem of causal inference is that we can either see a unit’s treated or untreated potential outcomes (but not both)
However, with panel data “natural experiment” setting above, this is not 100% true.
We can see both a unit’s treated and untreated potential outcome outcome…just at different points in time
This seems extremely useful for learning about causal effects
Modern approaches also typically allow for treatment effect heterogeneity
This is going to be a major issue in the discussion below
We’ll consider implications for “traditional” regression approaches and how new approaches are designed to handle this
Data:
2 periods: \(t=1\), \(t=2\)
\(D_{it}\) treatment indicator in period \(t\)
2 groups: \(G_i=1\) or \(G_i=0\) (treated and untreated)
Potential Outcomes: \(Y_{it}(1)\) and \(Y_{it}(0)\)
Observed Outcomes: \(Y_{it=2}\) and \(Y_{it=1}\)
\[\begin{align*} Y_{it=2} = G_i Y_{it=2}(1) +(1-G_i)Y_{it=2}(0) \quad \textrm{and} \quad Y_{it=1} = Y_{it=1}(0) \end{align*}\]
Average Treatment Effect on the Treated: \[ATT = \E[Y_{t=2}(1) - Y_{t=2}(0) | G=1]\]
Explanation: Mean difference between treated and untreated potential outcomes in the second period among the treated group
Notice that: \[\begin{align*} ATT = \underbrace{\E[Y_{t=2}(1) | G=1]}_{\textrm{Easy}} - \underbrace{\E[Y_{t=2}(0) | G=1]}_{\textrm{Hard}} \end{align*}\]
With panel data, we can re-write this as
\[\begin{align*} ATT = \color{green}{\E[Y_{t=2}(1) - Y_{t=1}(0) | G=1]} - \color{red}{\E[Y_{t=2}(0) - Y_{t=1}(0) | G=1]} \end{align*}\]
The first term is how outcomes changed over time for the treated group
Notice that: in our “natural experiment” setting, this is a difference between treated and untreated potential outcomes
We can directly estimate this from the data
Notice that: \[\begin{align*} ATT = \underbrace{\E[Y_{t=2}(1) | G=1]}_{\textrm{Easy}} - \underbrace{\E[Y_{t=2}(0) | G=1]}_{\textrm{Hard}} \end{align*}\]
With panel data, we can re-write this as
\[\begin{align*} ATT = \color{green}{\E[Y_{t=2}(1) - Y_{t=1}(0) | G=1]} - \color{red}{\E[Y_{t=2}(0) - Y_{t=1}(0) | G=1]} \end{align*}\]
The second term is how outcomes would have changed over time if the treated group had not been treated
Notice that: \[\begin{align*} ATT = \underbrace{\E[Y_{t=2}(1) | G=1]}_{\textrm{Easy}} - \underbrace{\E[Y_{t=2}(0) | G=1]}_{\textrm{Hard}} \end{align*}\]
With panel data, we can re-write this as
\[\begin{align*} ATT = \color{green}{\E[Y_{t=2}(1) - Y_{t=1}(0) | G=1]} - \color{red}{\E[Y_{t=2}(0) - Y_{t=1}(0) | G=1]} \end{align*}\]
The second term is how outcomes would have changed over time if the treated group had not been treated
This is not directly observed in the data \(\implies\) we need to make identifying assumptions
There are many possibilities here:
Notice that: \[\begin{align*} ATT = \underbrace{\E[Y_{t=2}(1) | G=1]}_{\textrm{Easy}} - \underbrace{\E[Y_{t=2}(0) | G=1]}_{\textrm{Hard}} \end{align*}\]
With panel data, we can re-write this as
\[\begin{align*} ATT = \color{green}{\E[Y_{t=2}(1) - Y_{t=1}(0) | G=1]} - \color{red}{\E[Y_{t=2}(0) - Y_{t=1}(0) | G=1]} \end{align*}\]
The second term is how outcomes would have changed over time if the treated group had not been treated
This is not directly observed in the data \(\implies\) we need to make identifying assumptions
There are many possibilities here:
Notice that: \[\begin{align*} ATT = \underbrace{\E[Y_{t=2}(1) | G=1]}_{\textrm{Easy}} - \underbrace{\E[Y_{t=2}(0) | G=1]}_{\textrm{Hard}} \end{align*}\]
With panel data, we can re-write this as
\[\begin{align*} ATT = \color{green}{\E[Y_{t=2}(1) - Y_{t=1}(0) | G=1]} - \color{red}{\E[Y_{t=2}(0) - Y_{t=1}(0) | G=1]} \end{align*}\]
The second term is how outcomes would have changed over time if the treated group had not been treated
This is not directly observed in the data \(\implies\) we need to make identifying assumptions
There are many possibilities here:
Parallel Trends Assumption
\[\color{red}{\E[\Delta Y(0) | G=1]} = \E[\Delta Y(0) | G=0]\]
Explanation: Mean path of untreated potential outcomes is the same for the treated group as for the untreated group
Identification: Under PTA, we can identify \(ATT\): \[ \begin{aligned} ATT &= \E[\Delta Y | G=1] - \E[\Delta Y(0) | G=1] \end{aligned} \]
Parallel Trends Assumption
\[\color{red}{\E[\Delta Y(0) | G=1]} = \E[\Delta Y(0) | G=0]\]
Explanation: Mean path of untreated potential outcomes is the same for the treated group as for the untreated group
Identification: Under PTA, we can identify \(ATT\): \[ \begin{aligned} ATT &= \E[\Delta Y | G=1] - \E[\Delta Y(0) | G=1]\\ &= \E[\Delta Y | G=1] - \E[\Delta Y | G=0] \end{aligned} \]
\(\implies ATT\) is identified can be recovered by the difference in outcomes over time (difference 1) relative to the difference in outcomes over time for the untreated group (difference 2)
The most straightforward approach to estimation is plugin:
\[\widehat{ATT} = \frac{1}{n_1} \sum_{i=1}^n G_i \Delta Y_i - \frac{1}{n_0} \sum_{i=1}^n (1-G_i) \Delta Y_i\]
Alternatively, TWFE regression: \[Y_{it} = \theta_t + \eta_i + \alpha D_{it} + e_{it}\]
It’s easy to make the TWFE regression more complicated:
Multiple time periods
Variation in treatment timing
More complicated treatments
Introducing additional covariates
Unfortunately, the robustness of TWFE regressions to treatment effect heterogeneity or these more complicated (and empirically relevant) settings does not seem to hold
Much of the recent (mostly negative) literature on TWFE in the context of DID has considered these types of “realistic” settings
Next, we will consider one of these settings: staggered treatment adoption
\(\T\) time periods
Staggered treatment adoption: Units can become treated at different points in time, but once a unit becomes treated, it remains treated.
Examples:
Government policies that roll out in different locations at different times (minimum wage is close to this over short time horizons)
“Scarring” treatments: e.g., job displacement does not typically happen year after year, but rather labor economists think of being displaced as changing a person’s “state” (the treatment is more like: has a person ever been displaced)
Notation:
In math, staggered treatment adoption means: \(D_{it-1}=1 \implies D_{it}=1\).
\(G_i\) — a unit’s group — the time period that unit becomes treated.
Define \(U_i=1\) for never-treated units and \(U_i=0\) otherwise.
Notation (cont’d):
Group-time average treatment effects \[\begin{align*} ATT(g,t) = \E[Y_t(g) - Y_t(0) | G=g] \end{align*}\]
Explanation: \(ATT\) for group \(g\) in time period \(t\)
Event Study \[\begin{align*} ATT^{es}(e) = \E[ Y_{g+e}(G) - Y_{g+e}(0) | G \in \mathcal{G}_e] \end{align*}\]
where \(\mathcal{G}_e\) is the set of groups observed to have experienced the treatment for \(e\) periods at some point.
Explanation: \(ATT\) when units have been treated for \(e\) periods
Overall ATT
Towards this end: the average treatment effect for unit \(i\) (across its post-treatment time periods) is given by: \[\bar{\tau}_i(G_i) = \frac{1}{\T - G_i + 1} \sum_{t=G_i}^{\T} \Big( Y_{it}(G_i) - Y_{it}(0) \Big)\]
Then,
\[\begin{align*} ATT^o = \E[\bar{\tau}(G) | U=0] \end{align*}\]
Explanation: \(ATT\) across all units that every participate in the treatment
⟶
⟶
To understand the discussion later, it is also helpful to think of \(ATT(g,t)\) as a building block for the other parameters discussed above. For example:
Overall ATT \[\begin{align*} ATT^o = \sum_{g \in \bar{\mathcal{G}}} \sum_{t=g}^{\T} w^o(g,t) ATT(g,t) \qquad \qquad \textrm{where} \quad w^o(g,t) = \frac{\P(G=g|U=0)}{\T-g+1} \end{align*}\]
Likewise, can show that \(ATT^{es}(e)\) is a weighted average of \(ATT(g,g+e)\)
\(\implies\) If we can identify/recover \(ATT(g,t)\), then we can proceed to recover \(ATT^{es}(e)\) and \(ATT^o\).
Multiple Period Version of Parallel Trends Assumption
For all groups \(g \in \bar{\mathcal{G}}\) (all groups except the never-treated group) and for all time periods \(t=2,\ldots,\T\), \[\begin{align*} \E[\Delta Y_{t}(0) | G=g] = \E[\Delta Y_{t}(0) | U=1] \end{align*}\]
Using very similar arguments as before, can show that \[\begin{align*} ATT(g,t) = \E[Y_{t} - Y_{g-1} | G=g] - \E[Y_{t} - Y_{g-1} | U=1] \end{align*}\]
where the main difference is that we use \((g-1)\) as the base period (this is the period right before group \(g\) becomes treated).
The previous discussion emphasizes a general purpose identification strategy with staggered treatment adoption:
Step 1: Target disaggregated treatment effect parameters (i.e., group-time average treatment effects)
Step 2: (If desired) combine disaggregated treatment effects into lower dimensional summary treatment effect parameter
Notice that:
This amounts to breaking the problem into a set of two-period DID problems and then combining the results
It is also a general purpose strategy in that the same high-level idea is (1) not DID-specific and (2) can (possibly) be applied to more complicated treatment regimes
With staggered treatments, traditionally DID identification strategies have been implemented with two-way fixed effects (TWFE) regressions: \[\begin{align*} Y_{it} = \theta_t + \eta_i + \alpha D_{it} + e_{it} \end{align*}\]
One main contribution of recent work on DID has been to diagnose and understand the limitations of TWFE regressions for implementing DID
Goodman-Bacon (2021) intuition: \(\alpha\) “comes from” comparisons between the path of outcomes for units whose treatment status changes relative to the path of outcomes for units whose treatment status stays the same over time.
Some comparisons are for groups that become treated to not-yet-treated groups 👍
Other comparisons are for groups that become treated relative to already-treated groups 👎
de Chaisemartin and D’Haultfœuille (2020) intuition: You can write \(\alpha\) as a weighted average of \(ATT(g,t)\)
First, a decomposition: \[\begin{align*} \alpha &= \sum_{g \in \bar{\mathcal{G}}} \sum_{t=g}^{\T} w^{TWFE}(g,t) \Big( \E[(Y_{t} - Y_{g-1}) | G=g] - \E[(Y_{t} - Y_{g-1}) | U=1] \Big) \\ & + \sum_{g \in \bar{\mathcal{G}}} \sum_{t=1}^{g-1} w^{TWFE}(g,t) \Big( \E[(Y_{t} - Y_{g-1}) | G=g] - \E[(Y_{t} - Y_{g-1}) | U=1] \Big) \end{align*}\]
Second, under parallel trends: \[\begin{align*} \alpha = \sum_{g \in \bar{\mathcal{G}}} \sum_{t=g}^{\T} w^{TWFE}(g,t) ATT(g,t) \end{align*}\]
But the weights are (non-transparently) driven by the estimation method
These weights have some good / bad / strange properties such as possibly being negative
We’ll discuss:
Intuition: Directly implement the identification result discussed above
\[\begin{align*} ATT(g,t) = \E[Y_{t} - Y_{g-1} | G=g] - \E[Y_{t} - Y_{g-1} | U=1] \end{align*}\]
Estimation:
\[\begin{align*}\widehat{ATT}^{CS}(g,t) = \frac{1}{n_g}\sum_{i=1}^n \indicator{G_i = g}(Y_{it} - Y_{ig-1}) - \frac{1}{n_U}\sum_{i=1}^n \indicator{U_i = 1} (Y_{it} - Y_{ig-1}) \end{align*}\]
2nd step: Recall: group-time average treatment effects are building blocks for more aggregated parameters such as \(ATT^{es}(e)\) and \(ATT^o\) \(\implies\) just plug in
Intuition: Paper points out limitations of event-study versions of the TWFE regressions discussed above:
\[\begin{align*} Y_{it} = \theta_t + \eta_i + \sum_{e=-(\T-1)}^{-2} \beta_e D_{it}^e + \sum_{e=0}^{\T} \beta_e D_{it}^e + e_{it} \end{align*}\]
and points out similar issues. In particular, the event study regression is “underspecified” \(\implies\) heterogeneous effects can “confound” the treatment effect estimates
Solution: Run fully interacted regression: \[\begin{align*} Y_{it} = \theta_t + \eta_i + \sum_{g \in \bar{\mathcal{G}}} \sum_{e \neq -1} \delta^{SA}_{ge} \indicator{G_i=g} \indicator{g+e=t} + e_{it} \end{align*}\]
2nd step: Aggregate \(\delta^{SA}_{ge}\)’s across groups (usually into an event study).
This sidesteps issues with the event study regression coming from treatment effect heterogeneity
For inference, need to account for two-step estimation procedure
Intuition: Are issues in DID literature due to limitations of TWFE regressions per se or due to misspecification of TWFE regression?
Solution: Proposes running “more interacted” TWFE regression:
\[\begin{align*} Y_{it} = \theta_t + \eta_i + \sum_{g \in \bar{\mathcal{G}}} \sum_{s=g}^{\T} \alpha_{gt}^W \indicator{G_i=g, t=s} + e_{it} \end{align*}\]
This is quite similar to Sun and Abraham (2021) except for that it doesn’t include interactions in pre-treatment periods. [The differences about \((g,t)\) relative to \((g,e)\) are trivial.]
Like SA, this provides robustness to treatment effect heterogeneity by including more interactions
Like SA, unless mainly interested in \(ATT(g,t)\), have to do second step aggregation that (arguably) ends the “killer feature” of the TWFE regression to begin with
Intuition: Parallel trends is closely connected to a TWFE model for untreated potential outcomes \[Y_{it}(0) = \theta_t + \eta_i + e_{it}\]
Estimation:
Step 1: Split data into treated and untreated observations
Step 2: Estimate above model for the set of untreated observations
Step 3: “Impute” \(\hat{Y}_{it}(0) = \hat{\theta}_t + \hat{\eta}_i\) for the treated observations
\(\displaystyle \widehat{ATT}^{G/BJS}(g,t) = \frac{1}{n_g} \sum_{i=1}^n \indicator{G_i=g}\Big(Y_{it} - \hat{Y}_{it}(0)\Big) \xrightarrow{p} ATT(g,t)\)
Can compute other treatment effect parameters too (e.g., event study or overall average treatment effect)
In my view, all of the approaches discussed above are fundamentally similar to each other.
In practice, it is sometimes possible to get different results though this is often driven by
Different estimation strategies trading off efficiency and robustness in different ways
Different choices in terms of default implementation details in computer code
In post-treatment periods, these give numerically identical results: \(\widehat{ATT}^{CS}(g,t) = \hat{\delta}^{SA}_{t,t-g}\)
In pre-treatment periods, code will give different pre-treatment estimates, but this is due to different default choices
In SA, all results are relative to a fixed base period (typically the period right before treatment)
In CS, by default, in pre-treatment periods, estimates are of placebo policy effects on impact (i.e., the base period is always the most recent pre-treatment period)
These are clearly closely related, with the difference amounting to whether or not one includes indicators for pre-treatment periods.
It is fair to see this as a way to trade-off robustness and efficiency
If parallel trends holds across all time periods, then Wooldridge can tend to deliver more efficient estimates (as effectively all pre-treatment periods are used as base periods)
If parallel trends is violated in some pre-treatment periods but holds post-treatment, Wooldridge estimates will be inconsistent, but SA estimates will be robust to violations of parallel trends in pre-treatment periods.
See Harmon (2023) for more details
Wooldridge and Gardner/BJS give numerically the same estimates: \(\hat{\alpha}^W_{gt} = \widehat{ATT}^{G/BJS}(g,t)\)
Intuition: Including full set of interactions is equivalent to estimating separate models by groups
The above discussion emphasizes the conceptual similarities between different proposed alternatives to TWFE regressions in the literature.
The other major source of differences in estimates across procedures is different default options in software implementations. Examples:
The above discussion emphasizes the conceptual similarities between different proposed alternatives to TWFE regressions in the literature.
The other major source of differences in estimates across procedures is different default options in software implementations. Examples:
The above discussion emphasizes the conceptual similarities between different proposed alternatives to TWFE regressions in the literature.
The other major source of differences in estimates across procedures is different default options in software implementations. Examples:
Exploit minimum wage changes across states
Goals:
Get some experience with an application and DID-related code
Assess how much do the issues that we have been talking about matter in practice
Full code is available on GitHub.
R packages used in empirical example
# drops NE region and a couple of small groups
mw_data_ch2 <- subset(mw_data_ch2, (G %in% c(2004,2006,2007,0)) & (region != "1"))
head(mw_data_ch2[,c("id","year","G","lemp","lpop","lavg_pay","region")])
id year G lemp lpop lavg_pay region
554 8003 2001 2007 5.556828 9.614137 10.05750 4
555 8003 2002 2007 5.356586 9.623972 10.09712 4
556 8003 2003 2007 5.389072 9.620859 10.10761 4
557 8003 2004 2007 5.356586 9.626548 10.14034 4
558 8003 2005 2007 5.303305 9.637958 10.17550 4
559 8003 2006 2007 5.342334 9.633056 10.21859 4
attgt <- did::att_gt(yname="lemp",
idname="id",
gname="G",
tname="year",
data=data2,
control_group="nevertreated",
base_period="universal")
tidy(attgt)[,1:5] # print results, drop some extra columns
term group time estimate std.error
1 ATT(2004,2003) 2004 2003 0.00000000 NA
2 ATT(2004,2004) 2004 2004 -0.03266653 0.020852124
3 ATT(2004,2005) 2004 2005 -0.06827991 0.021552525
4 ATT(2004,2006) 2004 2006 -0.12335404 0.020854023
5 ATT(2004,2007) 2004 2007 -0.13109136 0.022665540
6 ATT(2006,2003) 2006 2003 -0.03408910 0.011645871
7 ATT(2006,2004) 2006 2004 -0.01669977 0.008271849
8 ATT(2006,2005) 2006 2005 0.00000000 NA
9 ATT(2006,2006) 2006 2006 -0.01939335 0.009368453
10 ATT(2006,2007) 2006 2007 -0.06607568 0.009591020
Call:
did::aggte(MP = attgt, type = "group")
Reference: Callaway, Brantly and Pedro H.C. Sant'Anna. "Difference-in-Differences with Multiple Time Periods." Journal of Econometrics, Vol. 225, No. 2, pp. 200-230, 2021. <https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jeconom.2020.12.001>, <https://arxiv.org/abs/1803.09015>
Overall summary of ATT's based on group/cohort aggregation:
ATT Std. Error [ 95% Conf. Int.]
-0.0571 0.0086 -0.074 -0.0401 *
Group Effects:
Group Estimate Std. Error [95% Simult. Conf. Band]
2004 -0.0888 0.0195 -0.1336 -0.0441 *
2006 -0.0427 0.0079 -0.0609 -0.0246 *
---
Signif. codes: `*' confidence band does not cover 0
Control Group: Never Treated, Anticipation Periods: 0
Estimation Method: Doubly Robust
The differences between the CS estimates and the TWFE estimates are fairly large here: the CS estimate is about 50% larger than the TWFE estimate, though results are qualitatively similar.
To summarize: \(ATT^o = -0.057\) while \(\alpha^{TWFE} = -0.038\). This difference can be fully accounted for
Pre-treatment differences in paths of outcomes across groups: explains about 64% of the difference
Differences in weights applied to the same post-treatment \(ATT(g,t)\): explains about 36% of the difference. [If you apply the post-treatment weights and “zero out” pre-treatment differences, the estimate would be \(-0.050\).]
In my experience: this is fairly representative of how much new DID approaches matter relative to TWFE regressions. It does not seem like “catastrophic failure” of TWFE, but (in my view) these are meaningful differences (and, e.g., given slightly different \(ATT(g,t)\)’s, the difference in the weighting schemes could change the qualitative results).
One more comment: there is a lot concern about negative weights (both in econometrics and empirical work).
data3
(the data that includes \(G_i=2007\)), you will get a negative weight on \(ATT(g=2004,t=2007)\). But it turns out not to matter much, and TWFE works better in this case than in the case that I showed you.Not a Panacea
Possible Disadvantages:
Advantages:
Off-the-shelf robust to treatment effect heterogeneity
Arguably, simpler and more transparent
Direct implementation of the DID identification strategy
View #1: Parallel trends as a purely reduced form assumption
But this is certainly not the only possibility:
In some disciplines (e.g., biostats) it is relatively more common to assume unconfoundedness conditional on lagged outcomes (i.e., the LO approach above)
This is also what my undergraduate econometrics students almost always suggest (their judgement is not clouded by having thought about these things too much)
Or, alternatively, why not take two differences instead of one…
In my view, these seem like fair points
View #2: Models that lead to parallel trends assumption. We’ll focus on untreated potential outcomes): \[Y_{it}(0) = \theta_t + \eta_i + e_{it}\] Parallel trends is equivalent to this model along with the condition that \(\E[e_t | G] = 0\).
Many economic models have this sort of flavor, that the important thing driving differences in outcomes is some latent characteristic (differences in lagged outcomes may proxy this, but not the “deep” explanation)
Pros
No restrictions on treatment effect heterogeneity
Can allow for some self-selection into treatment
View #2: Models that lead to parallel trends assumption. We’ll focus on untreated potential outcomes: \[Y_{it}(0) = \theta_t + \eta_i + e_{it}\] Parallel trends is equivalent to this model along with the condition that \(\E[e_t | G] = 0\).
Many economic models have this sort of flavor, that the important thing driving differences in outcomes is some latent characteristic (differences in lagged outcomes may proxy this, but not the “deep” explanation)
Cons: However, additive separability of \(\theta_t\) and \(\eta_i\) is crucial for identification
This is different from other natural experiment methods such as IV and RD, where at least from an identification perspective, there is not model-dependence
May not be plausible for limited dependent variables
Also related to results in Roth and Sant’Anna (2023) (about parallel trends and functional form) and Ghanem, Sant’Anna, and Wüthrich (2024) (about selection and parallel trends) [Back]
Consider a simplified setting where \(\T=2\), but we allow for there to be units that are already treated in the first period.
\(\implies\) 3 groups: \(G_i=1\), \(G_i=2\), \(G_i=\infty\)
Because there are only two periods, the TWFE regression is equivalent to the regression \[\begin{align*} \Delta Y_i = \Delta \theta_{t=2} + \alpha \Delta D_{it=2} + \Delta e_{it=2} \end{align*}\]
Moreover, \(\Delta D_{it=2}\) only takes two values:
\(\Delta D_{it=2} = 0\) for \(G_i=1\) and \(G_i=\infty\)
\(\Delta D_{it=2} = 1\) for \(G_i=2\)
Thus, this is a fully saturated regression, and we have that \[\begin{align*} \alpha = \E[\Delta Y | \Delta D_{t=2} = 1] - \E[\Delta Y | \Delta D_{t=2}=0] \end{align*}\]
Starting from the previous slide: \[\begin{align*} \alpha = \E[\Delta Y | \Delta D_{t=2} = 1] - \E[\Delta Y | \Delta D_{t=2}=0] \end{align*}\] and consider the term on the far right, we have that \[\begin{align*} \E[\Delta Y | \Delta D_{t=2}=0] = \E[\Delta Y | G=1] \underbrace{\frac{p_1}{p_1 + p_\infty}}_{=: w_1} + \E[\Delta Y | G=\infty] \underbrace{\frac{p_\infty}{p_1 + p_\infty}}_{=: w_\infty} \end{align*}\]
where \(w_1\) and \(w_\infty\) are the relative sizes of group 1 and the never treated group, and notice that \(w_1 + w_\infty = 1\). Plugging this back in \(\implies\) \[\begin{align*} \alpha = \Big( \E[\Delta Y | G=2] - \E[\Delta Y | G=1]\Big) w_1 + \Big( \E[\Delta Y | G=2] - \E[\Delta Y|G=\infty]\Big) w_\infty \end{align*}\]
This is exactly the Goodman-Bacon result! \(\alpha\) is a weighted average of all possible 2x2 comparisons
Let’s keep going: \[\begin{align*} \alpha = \underbrace{\Big( \E[\Delta Y | G=2] - \E[\Delta Y | G=1]\Big)}_{\textrm{What is this?}} w_1 + \underbrace{\Big( \E[\Delta Y | G=2] - \E[\Delta Y|G=\infty]\Big)}_{ATT(2,2)} w_\infty \end{align*}\] Working on the first term, we have that \[ \begin{aligned} & \E[\Delta Y_{2} | G=2] - \E[\Delta Y_{2} | G=1] \hspace{300pt} \end{aligned} \]
Let’s keep going: \[\begin{align*} \alpha = \underbrace{\Big( \E[\Delta Y | G=2] - \E[\Delta Y | G=1]\Big)}_{\textrm{What is this?}} w_1 + \underbrace{\Big( \E[\Delta Y | G=2] - \E[\Delta Y|G=\infty]\Big)}_{ATT(2,2)} w_\infty \end{align*}\] Working on the first term, we have that \[ \begin{aligned} & \E[\Delta Y_{2} | G=2] - \E[\Delta Y_{2} | G=1] \hspace{300pt}\\ &\hspace{10pt} = \E[Y_{2}(2) - Y_{1}(\infty) | G=2] - \E[Y_{2}(1) - Y_{1}(1) | G=1] \end{aligned} \]
Let’s keep going: \[\begin{align*} \alpha = \underbrace{\Big( \E[\Delta Y | G=2] - \E[\Delta Y | G=1]\Big)}_{\textrm{What is this?}} w_1 + \underbrace{\Big( \E[\Delta Y | G=2] - \E[\Delta Y|G=\infty]\Big)}_{ATT(2,2)} w_\infty \end{align*}\] Working on the first term, we have that \[ \begin{aligned} & \E[\Delta Y_{2} | G=2] - \E[\Delta Y_{2} | G=1] \hspace{300pt}\\ &\hspace{10pt} = \E[Y_{2}(2) - Y_{1}(\infty) | G=2] - \E[Y_{2}(1) - Y_{1}(1) | G=1] \\ &\hspace{10pt} = \E[Y_{2}(2) - Y_{2}(\infty) | G=2] + \underline{\E[Y_{2}(\infty) - Y_{1}(\infty) | G=2]} \end{aligned} \]
Let’s keep going: \[\begin{align*} \alpha = \underbrace{\Big( \E[\Delta Y | G=2] - \E[\Delta Y | G=1]\Big)}_{\textrm{What is this?}} w_1 + \underbrace{\Big( \E[\Delta Y | G=2] - \E[\Delta Y|G=\infty]\Big)}_{ATT(2,2)} w_\infty \end{align*}\] Working on the first term, we have that \[ \begin{aligned} & \E[\Delta Y_{2} | G=2] - \E[\Delta Y_{2} | G=1] \hspace{300pt}\\ &\hspace{10pt} = \E[Y_{2}(2) - Y_{1}(\infty) | G=2] - \E[Y_{2}(1) - Y_{1}(1) | G=1] \\ &\hspace{10pt} = \E[Y_{2}(2) - Y_{2}(\infty) | G=2] + \underline{\E[Y_{2}(\infty) - Y_{1}(\infty) | G=2]}\\ &\hspace{20pt} - \Big( \E[Y_{2}(1) - Y_{2}(\infty) | G=1] - \E[Y_{1}(1) - Y_{1}(\infty) | G=1] + \underline{\E[Y_{2}(\infty) - Y_{1}(\infty) | G=1]} \Big) \end{aligned} \]
Let’s keep going: \[\begin{align*} \alpha = \underbrace{\Big( \E[\Delta Y | G=2] - \E[\Delta Y | G=1]\Big)}_{\textrm{What is this?}} w_1 + \underbrace{\Big( \E[\Delta Y | G=2] - \E[\Delta Y|G=\infty]\Big)}_{ATT(2,2)} w_\infty \end{align*}\] Working on the first term, we have that \[ \begin{aligned} & \E[\Delta Y_{2} | G=2] - \E[\Delta Y_{2} | G=1] \hspace{300pt}\\ &\hspace{10pt} = \E[Y_{2}(2) - Y_{1}(\infty) | G=2] - \E[Y_{2}(1) - Y_{1}(1) | G=1] \\ &\hspace{10pt} = \E[Y_{2}(2) - Y_{2}(\infty) | G=2] + \underline{\E[Y_{2}(\infty) - Y_{1}(\infty) | G=2]}\\ &\hspace{20pt} - \Big( \E[Y_{2}(1) - Y_{2}(\infty) | G=1] - \E[Y_{1}(1) - Y_{1}(\infty) | G=1] + \underline{\E[Y_{2}(\infty) - Y_{1}(\infty) | G=1]} \Big)\\ &\hspace{10pt} = \underbrace{ATT(2,2)}_{\textrm{causal effect}} - \underbrace{\Big(ATT(1,2) - ATT(1,1)\Big)}_{\textrm{treatment effect dynamics}} \end{aligned} \]
Plug this expression back in \(\rightarrow\)
Plugging the previous expression back in, we have that \[\begin{align*} \alpha = ATT(2,2) + ATT(1,1) w_1 + ATT(1,2)(-w_1) \end{align*}\]
This is exactly the result in de Chaisemartin and d’Haultfoeuille! \(\alpha\) is equal to a weighted average of \(ATT(g,t)\)’s, but it is possible that some of the weights can be negative.
Also, as they point out, a sufficient condition for the weights to be non-negative is: no treatment effect dynamics \(\implies ATT(1,1) = ATT(1,2)\) \(\overset{\textrm{here}}{\implies} \alpha = ATT(2,2)\).
[Back]
Consider the following alternative aggregated treatment effect parameter \[\begin{align*} ATT^{simple} := \sum_{t=g}^\T ATT(g,t) \frac{\P(G=g | G \in \bar{\mathcal{G}})}{\sum_{t=g}^{\T} \P(G=g| G \in \bar{\mathcal{G}})} \end{align*}\] Consider imputation so that you have \(Y_{it}-\hat{Y}_{it}(0)\) available in all periods. This is the \(ATT\) parameter that you get by averaging all of those.
Relative to \(ATT^o\), early treated units get more weight (because we have more \(Y_{it}-\hat{Y}_{it}(0)\) for them).
By construction, weights are all positive. However, they are different from \(ATT^o\) weights
Besides the violations of parallel trends in pre-treatment periods, these weights are further away from \(ATT^o\) than the TWFE regression weights are!
In fact, you calculate \(ATT^{simple} = -0.065\) (13% larger in magnitude that \(ATT^o\))
Finally, if you are “content with” non-negative weights, then you can get any summary measure from \(-0.019\) (the smallest \(ATT(g,t)\)) to \(-0.13\) (the largest). This is a wide range of estimates.
In my view, the discussion above suggests that clearly stating a target aggregate treatment effect parameter and choosing weights that target that parameter is probably more important than checking for negative weights
[Back]
Comments
The above discussion emphasizes the conceptual similarities between different proposed alternatives to TWFE regressions in the literature.
The other major source of differences in estimates across procedures is different default options in software implementations. Examples: